We’re still dancing: How bubbles grow

Authored by

Owen A. Lamont, Ph.D.

Senior Vice President, Portfolio Manager, Research

In THERE ARE IDIOTS: Seven pillars of market bubbles, I gave seven phrases of timeless relevance for the origins of bubbles. Here, I ask what happens after the bubble has started; what keeps bubbles bubbling? I discuss seven more phrases:

  1. We’re still dancing.
  2. There’s a sucker born every minute.
  3. A happy opportunity for ingenious mendacity.
  4. Man is always a teller of tales.
  5. Have fun staying poor.
  6. Don’t fight the tape.
  7. Ride the whirlwind.

1. “We’re still dancing.”

To have a speculative bubble, you need two things: something to trade and somewhere to trade it. You can’t have a Beanie Baby bubble in 1997 without a firm that makes Beanie Babies (Ty Inc.) and a trading venue (Ebay, among others).

Bubbles need institutions. In the tech-stock bubble, the institutions were mainly investment banks (underwriting IPOs) and growth funds (buying IPOs). In the crypto bubble of 2021, the institutions were mainly offshore crypto exchanges. Today, we see major financial institutions embracing crypto. How will it end?

Here’s Citigroup[1] CEO Chuck Prince in July 2007, echoing a famous passage in The General Theory where Keynes compares the stock market to a game of musical chairs:[2]

When the music stops, in terms of liquidity, things will be complicated. But as long as the music is playing, you’ve got to get up and dance. We’re still dancing.

Prince was discussing lending to private equity, but it’s a classic dilemma: should institutions enable market bubbles that will probably end badly for their clients? That is, do institutions really have to get up and dance when the music’s playing?

Benjamin Graham thought underwriters behaved badly. Graham and Dodd (1934) said the wave of issuance in 1929 was “a wholesale and disastrous relaxation of the standard of safety previously observed by the reputable houses of issue.” Graham (1973) said the wave in 1969 was an “unprecedented outpouring of issues of lowest quality, sold to the public at absurdly high offering prices and in many cases pushed much higher by heedless speculation...the familiar combination of greed, folly, and irresponsibility.”

Let’s compare the actions of two large institutions as of today. Blackrock launched a highly successful bitcoin ETF in January 2024. In contrast, Vanguard has so far refused to enter the crypto space and will not even allow its customers to buy crypto ETFs offered by others.

Is Vanguard engaged in heavy-handed paternalism? Isn’t the customer always right? Perhaps not. Consider Vanguard's actions in 1999, when it saw inflows into the Vanguard Growth Index Fund:[3]

The company grew so worried that its customers were buying the growth fund for the wrong reason that it temporarily accompanied its prospectuses with a warning letter. As Jack Bogle uneasily admitted, Vanguard’s anxiety about the fund’s shareholders was justified. By December 2001, the fund had not only shed its previous gains, but it was suffering net redemptions.

Perhaps the lesson here is that fools rush in where Vanguard fears to tread.

Right now, one thing’s for sure. Blackrock is dancing. Vanguard remains seated, arms crossed, glaring at the DJ.

2. “There’s a sucker born every minute.”

Bubbles typically involve a wave of credulous buyers, an influx of inexperienced investors that I call The Fourth Horseman of the bubble. As P.T. Barnum supposedly said, there’s a sucker born every minute.

One bitcoin advocate, Matthew Sigel of VanEck, went on CNBC in October 2024 and justified his price target of $3 million for bitcoin as follows:[4]

… new buyers come into the market. Every day there’s new buyers being born.

Now, he didn’t actually use the word “suckers,” but perhaps that’s implied by his $3 million price target.

We observe waves of new entrants in stock market bubbles as measured by the opening of new brokerage accounts, including two recent bubbles in China and the 2021 U.S. bubble involving Robinhood customers. Greenwood and Nagel (2009) found that the tech-stock bubble was partly driven by inexperienced mutual fund managers, and they mention other historical examples:

Kindleberger (1979) argues that bubbles bring in “segments of the population that are normally aloof from such ventures.” Recalling the 17th century tulip bubble, Mackay (1852) reports that “even chimney-sweeps and old clotheswomen dabbled in tulips.” Brooks’ (1973) depiction of the stock market boom of the late 1960s is that “Youth had taken over Wall Street.”

When you see chimneysweeps touting bitcoin on CNBC, it’s time to sell.

3. “A happy opportunity for ingenious mendacity.”

Bubbles typically involve fraud and lots of it. Here’s Bagehot (1873):

The good times too of high price almost always engender much fraud. All people are most credulous when they are most happy; and when much money has just been made, when some people are really making it, when most people think they are making it, there is a happy opportunity for ingenious mendacity. Almost everything will be believed for a little while …

Kedia and Philippon (2009) find that “periods of high stock market valuations are systematically followed by large increases in reported frauds” and show that the tech-stock bubble was accompanied by a wave of accounting fraud. Some of this fraud was committed by actors that have since left the scene, such as Enron and its CEO Ken Lay, while some was allegedly committed by actors who remain in the spotlight, such as MicroStrategy and its founder Michael Saylor.[5]

Will today’s high crypto prices produce ingenious mendacity? So far, I’m seeing a lot of mendacity but not much ingenuity.

4. “Man is always a teller of tales.”

Shiller (2017) discusses how bubbles are powered by contagious narratives spreading through the population, and quotes Sartre:

A man is always a teller of tales, he lives surrounded by his stories and the stories of others, he sees everything that happens to him through them; and he tries to live his life as if he were recounting it.

Today’s economy is not about factories and farms; it’s about narratives and attention. And crypto has the ultimate narrative. Here are the main story elements:

  • A decadent empire, corrupt and cruel (fiat currency and traditional banks).
  • A leader with mysterious origins (Satoshi Nakamoto).
  • Rebels fighting the empire, aided by mystical forces beyond human understanding (cryptography).

Crypto basically has the same plot as Star Wars, Dune, and The Matrix.

Most narratives eventually lose box office appeal, but for now, we’re living in the Bitcoin Cinematic Universe.

5. “Have fun staying poor.”

Shiller (2005) defines a bubble as “a situation in which news of price increases spurs investor enthusiasm, which spreads by psychological contagion from person to person, in the process amplifying stories that might justify the price increases, and bringing in a larger and larger class of investors who, despite doubts about the real value of an investment, are drawn to it partly by envy of others' successes and partly through a gamblers' excitement.”

Let’s discuss contagion and envy. We see both elements in the quip by Kindleberger (1979) that “there is nothing so disturbing to one’s well-being and judgment as to see a friend get rich.”

“Have fun staying poor” is a dismissive put-down made by bulls to denigrate bears. The phrase spreads contagiously via social media, and it is designed to trigger anticipatory envy in those who fail to buy. It communicates contempt for those too stupid, too old, or too cowardly to join the movement; they deserve to be poor.

Avoiding shame and derision is an age-old motive for participating in bubbles. Here’s poet Alexander Pope during the South Sea Bubble:

Let but Fortune favor us, & the World will be sure to admire our Prudence. If we fail, let’s e’en keep the mishap to ourselves; But tis Ignominious (in this Age of Hope and Golden Mountains) not to Venture.

Have fun staying ignominious.

6. “Don’t fight the tape.”

You might think that if an asset becomes overpriced, rational short sellers would enter. That’s not what happens in bubbles. Instead, we see the opposite: prices get crazy high and short sellers flee. For example, Lamont and Stein (2004) show short selling decreased during the tech-stock bubble.

Why do short sellers capitulate? Why don’t they fight the tape? Because of risk. Here’s Shleifer and Summers (1990):

As long as the arbitrageur is thinking of liquidating his position in the future, he must bear the risk that at that time stocks will be even more overpriced than they are today. If future mispricing is more extreme than when the arbitrage trade is put on, the arbitrageur suffers a loss on his position. Again, fear of this loss limits the size of the arbitrageur's initial position, and so keeps him from driving the price all the way down to fundamentals.

Crazy optimists create crazy price volatility, which scares away rational arbitrageurs. This dynamic explains why bubbles often involve high price volatility, and why bitcoin is both incredibly volatile and prone to bubbles.

What happens when you fight the tape? Nothing good. For example, betting on value and against growth in 1999 was a recipe for disaster, and many funds did not survive. The following passage from Lamont (2003) has a characteristically witty quote from someone who did survive 1999 and later prospered:

…it is clear in hindsight that NASDAQ was too high at 3000 in 1999. But anyone shorting NASDAQ then would have suffered severe losses as NASDAQ went to 5000 in March 2000. As hedge fund manager Cliff Asness has commented about short sale constraints, "Our problem wasn't that we couldn't short NASDAQ in 1999, our problem was that we could and did.”

He fought the tape, and the tape won.

7. “Ride the whirlwind.”

Bubbles can be magnified by rational investors who “ride the bubble,” the smart money that front-runs the dumb money arriving later. That’s the strategy suggested by George Soros, as quoted in Pedersen (2019):

When I see a bubble forming, I rush in to buy, adding fuel to the fire. This is not irrational.

Brunnermeier and Nagel (2004) show that hedge funds rode the tech-stock bubble, buying technology stocks between 1998 and 2000.

There is, however, a non-rational reason that sophisticated investors might buy: they just can’t resist. Consider this first-person account from Stanley Druckenmiller:[6]

So, I’ll never forget it. January of 2000 I go into Soros’s office and I say I’m selling all the tech stocks, selling everything. This is crazy …

So like around March I could feel it coming. I just – I had to play. I couldn’t help myself. And three times during the same week I pick up a – don’t do it. Don’t do it. Anyway, I pick up the phone finally. I think I missed the top by an hour. I bought $6 billion worth of tech stocks, and in six weeks I had left Soros and I had lost $3 billion in that one play. … I was just an emotional basket case and couldn’t help myself. 

“Ride the bubble” does not really capture the emotional rollercoaster induced by extreme price volatility. I think “ride the whirlwind” is a more apt phrase, as in Dickens (1841):

In the midst of thunder, lightning, and storm, many tremendous deeds have been committed; men, self-possessed before, have given a sudden loose to passions they could no longer control. The demons of wrath and despair have striven to emulate those who ride the whirlwind and direct the storm …

The idea that bubbles involve actual insanity has a long history. Consider the first bubble endured by the United States, the “Scripomania” of 1791. Here’s an account from Benjamin Rush, signer of the Declaration of Independence and physician, from Rush (1799):

The city of Philadelphia between the 10th and 11th of August 1791, will long be remembered by contemplative men, for having furnished the most extraordinary proofs of the stimulus of the love of money upon the human body … It excited febrile diseases in three persons who became my patients. In one of them, the acquisition of twelve thousand dollars in a few minutes by a lucky sale, brought on madness which terminated in death in a few days. The whole city felt the impulse of this paroxysm of avarice.

There you have it, friends. Do not ride the whirlwind, for it brings only madness and death.


Endnotes

[1] References to this and other companies should not be interpreted as recommendations to buy or sell specific securities. Acadian and/or the author of this post may hold positions in one or more securities associated with these companies.

[2] “Citigroup chief stays bullish on buy-outs,” The Financial Times, July 9, 2007.

[3] Rekenthaler, John. "Vanguard's Other Index-Fund Invention," Morningstar, May 27, 2022.

[4] “This is a very bullish setup for bitcoin into the election, says VanEck's Matthew Sigel,” CNBC, October 28, 2024.

[5] Norris, Floyd. “MicroStrategy Chairman Accused of Fraud by S.E.C.,” The New York Times, December 15, 2000.

[6] “Stanley Druckenmiller: My Biggest Mistake And What I Learned From It,” The Acquirer’s Multiple, July 9, 2018.

References

Bagehot, Walter. Lombard Street. 1873.

Brunnermeier, Markus, and Stefan Nagel. "Hedge funds and the technology bubble.” The Journal of Finance 59, no. 5 (2004): 2013-2040.

Dickens, Charles. Barnaby Rudge. 1841.

Graham, Benjamin. The Intelligent Investor, 1973.

Graham, Benjamin, and David L. Dodd. Security analysis: principles and technique. 1934.

Greenwood, Robin, and Stefan Nagel. "Inexperienced investors and bubbles." Journal of Financial Economics 93, no. 2 (2009): 239-258.

Kedia, Simi, and Thomas Philippon. "The economics of fraudulent accounting." The Review of Financial Studies 22, no. 6 (2009): 2169-2199.

Kindleberger, Charles P., Panics Manias, and Crashes. (1979).

Lamont, Owen A. "Comment on Perspectives on Behavioral Finance: Does ‘Irrationality’ Disappear with Wealth? Evidence from Expectations and Action" NBER Macroeconomics Annual 18 (2003): 200-207.

Lamont, Owen A., and Jeremy C. Stein. "Aggregate short interest and market valuations." American Economic Review 94, no. 2 (2004): 29-32.

Pedersen, Lasse Heje. Efficiently inefficient: how smart money invests and market prices are determined. Princeton University Press, 2019.

Rush, Benjamin. Three lectures upon animal life. 1799.

Shiller, Robert J. Irrational exuberance. 2005

Shiller, Robert J. "Narrative economics." American Economic Review 107, no. 4 (2017): 967-1004.

Shleifer, Andrei, and Lawrence H. Summers. "The noise trader approach to finance." Journal of Economic Perspectives 4, no. 2 (1990): 19-33.

Legal Disclaimer

These materials provided herein may contain material, non-public information within the meaning of the United States Federal Securities Laws with respect to Acadian Asset Management LLC, Acadian Asset Management Inc. and/or their respective subsidiaries and affiliated entities. The recipient of these materials agrees that it will not use any confidential information that may be contained herein to execute or recommend transactions in securities. The recipient further acknowledges that it is aware that United States Federal and State securities laws prohibit any person or entity who has material, non-public information about a publicly-traded company from purchasing or selling securities of such company, or from communicating such information to any other person or entity under circumstances in which it is reasonably foreseeable that such person or entity is likely to sell or purchase such securities.

Acadian provides this material as a general overview of the firm, our processes and our investment capabilities. It has been provided for informational purposes only. It does not constitute or form part of any offer to issue or sell, or any solicitation of any offer to subscribe or to purchase, shares, units or other interests in investments that may be referred to herein and must not be construed as investment or financial product advice. Acadian has not considered any reader's financial situation, objective or needs in providing the relevant information.

The value of investments may fall as well as rise and you may not get back your original investment. Past performance is not necessarily a guide to future performance or returns. Acadian has taken all reasonable care to ensure that the information contained in this material is accurate at the time of its distribution, no representation or warranty, express or implied, is made as to the accuracy, reliability or completeness of such information.

This material contains privileged and confidential information and is intended only for the recipient/s. Any distribution, reproduction or other use of this presentation by recipients is strictly prohibited. If you are not the intended recipient and this presentation has been sent or passed on to you in error, please contact us immediately. Confidentiality and privilege are not lost by this presentation having been sent or passed on to you in error.

Acadian’s quantitative investment process is supported by extensive proprietary computer code. Acadian’s researchers, software developers, and IT teams follow a structured design, development, testing, change control, and review processes during the development of its systems and the implementation within our investment process. These controls and their effectiveness are subject to regular internal reviews, at least annual independent review by our SOC1 auditor. However, despite these extensive controls it is possible that errors may occur in coding and within the investment process, as is the case with any complex software or data-driven model, and no guarantee or warranty can be provided that any quantitative investment model is completely free of errors. Any such errors could have a negative impact on investment results. We have in place control systems and processes which are intended to identify in a timely manner any such errors which would have a material impact on the investment process.

Acadian Asset Management LLC has wholly owned affiliates located in London, Singapore, and Sydney. Pursuant to the terms of service level agreements with each affiliate, employees of Acadian Asset Management LLC may provide certain services on behalf of each affiliate and employees of each affiliate may provide certain administrative services, including marketing and client service, on behalf of Acadian Asset Management LLC.

Acadian Asset Management LLC is registered as an investment adviser with the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. Registration of an investment adviser does not imply any level of skill or training.

Acadian Asset Management (Singapore) Pte Ltd, (Registration Number: 199902125D) is licensed by the Monetary Authority of Singapore. It is also registered as an investment adviser with the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission.

Acadian Asset Management (Australia) Limited (ABN 41 114 200 127) is the holder of Australian financial services license number 291872 ("AFSL"). It is also registered as an investment adviser with the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission. Under the terms of its AFSL, Acadian Asset Management (Australia) Limited is limited to providing the financial services under its license to wholesale clients only. This marketing material is not to be provided to retail clients.

Acadian Asset Management (UK) Limited is authorized and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority ('the FCA') and is a limited liability company incorporated in England and Wales with company number 05644066. Acadian Asset Management (UK) Limited will only make this material available to Professional Clients and Eligible Counterparties as defined by the FCA under the Markets in Financial Instruments Directive, or to Qualified Investors in Switzerland as defined in the Collective Investment Schemes Act, as applicable.

About the Author

Owen Lamont Acadian Asset Management

Owen A. Lamont, Ph.D.

Senior Vice President, Portfolio Manager, Research
Owen joined the Acadian investment team in 2023. In addition to more than 20 years of experience in asset management as a researcher and portfolio manager, Owen has been a member of the faculty at Harvard University, Princeton University, The University of Chicago Graduate School of Business, and Yale School of Management. His professional and academic focus is behavioral finance, and he has published papers on short selling, stock returns, and investor behavior in leading academic journals, and he has testified before the U.S. House of Representatives and the U.S. Senate. Owen earned a Ph.D. in economics from the Massachusetts Institute of Technology and a B.A. in economics and government from Oberlin College.